1. When tax revenues fall in a recession, state and local governments respond by cutting employment. Federal grants to states could avoid these layoffs by offsetting the budget shortfalls until the states’ revenues recover. We estimate that $50 billion in federal grants to state and  local governments would directly raise state and local employment in 2012 by about 150,000.

    In a recent Macro Focus we described our modest expectations for the effectiveness of provisions that might be included in a jobs bill the President will unveil after Labor Day. One possibility not discussed in that piece but finding some play in the press is extending federal grants-in-aid to states. Nearly all state governments face a balanced-budget mandate. Hence, when revenues fall during a recession, states respond with some combination of tax hikes and spending cuts. One way for states to cut spending is to lay off workers. Federal grants could forestall these layoffs.

    Using yearly average data since 1962, we ran a simple regression of the logarithmic change in S&L employment per capita on S&L deficits (NIPA definition, and expressed relative to S&L outlays) in the previous year.

    Our analysis shows that if this year, the federal government grants an additional $50 billion to S&L governments—roughly enough to eliminate the S&L deficits we project for next year—S&L employment will be boosted directly by 0.8% in 2012, or approximately 150,000 jobs. This implies that roughly $9 billion of the grants would be used to defend S&L jobs. The rest would be used to prevent other spending cuts or tax hikes at the state and local level. Hence, the remaining $41 billion would also boost employment indirectly by stimulating aggregate demand.

    That nearly 20% of the grants would go directly to jobs raises the relative power of grants as a jobs measure. For example, if states use the remaining $41 billion to prevent an increase in state personal taxes, the total impact on jobs in 2012 rises to around 290,000. This compares favorably to the 200,000 jobs we estimated would result in 2012 from extending unemployment benefits for another year at a greater cost of $60 billion.

    Contact Macroeconomic Advisers

  2. As we expected, there was no major news in Chairman Bernanke's remarks at Jackson Hole. In effect, the Chairman told symposium participants to enjoy the program, relax, and go hiking.

    He announced no new easing initiatives but signaled that the Committee has an easing bias.

    This is from a commentary that was published on August 26, 2011.

    Contact Macroeconomic Advisers
  3. We categorize the FOMC’s easing tools as either above the line (on the table, likely under consideration now) or below the line (off the table, at least for now).

    The dividing line between on-the-table and off-the-table options can shift depending on how the macro outlook evolves.

    This is from a commentary that was published on August 25, 2011.

    Contact Macroeconomic Advisers
  4. It may seem like there is an echo in the room. Recent changes in the growth outlook and stance of monetary policy are eerily similar to the circumstances surrounding last year's gathering at Jackson Hole. The Chairman's remarks may also be similar to last year's.

    This is from a commentary that was published on August 22, 2011.

    Contact Macroeconomic Advisers
  5. In principle, there is enough room in the Fed's portfolio for duration-extension strategies to provide significant additional monetary stimulus. But such strategies face a high threshold, though not as high as that for conventional large-scale asset purchases (LSAPs).

    This is from a commentary that was published on August 22, 2011.

    Contact Macroeconomic Advisers
  6. President Obama will unveil a new jobs plan shortly after Labor Day. Unofficial reports suggest it will include a combination of initiatives to increase hiring indirectly by stimulating aggregate demand, while simultaneously encouraging hiring with tax credits and training programs. These initiatives may include:
    • An extension of federal funding for emergency unemployment benefits
    • An extension of the payroll tax holiday, possibly expanded to include the employers' portion of Social Security taxes
    • An extension of temporary businesses "expensing" of capital investments
    • A new tax credit for businesses that increase the size of their workforce
    • Infrastructure spending, perhaps including renovation of public schools
    • A job-training program targeting the long-term unemployed, possibly modeled after a program in Georgia
    • To pay for these short-run initiatives, the President may seek more long-term deficit reduction than called for under the recent debt ceiling deal

    We estimate that extending through 2012 the employee payroll tax holiday, emergency unemployment benefits, and business expensing provisions would boost employment roughly 600,000 by the end of next year, with the effect quickly dissipating over the following two years. A temporary reduction in the employer payroll tax in 2012 may pull some employment forward from later years, as might a temporary tax credit for hiring, but we expect these effects to be negligible in such a weak economy. Infrastructure spending can make good economic sense in both the short-run and long-term, particularly at today's low interest rates, but takes time to ramp up and will be limited in scope by current political realities. Training programs could result in the faster re-employment of some workers, reducing structural unemployment. However, because none of these ideas address the main impediment to hiring-persistently insufficient final demand-our expectations for the success of a jobs bill are, well, not so great.



    EXTENDING UNEMPLOYMENT BENEFITS
    Roughly speaking, extending unemployment benefits through 2012 would cost $60 billion, boost real GDP growth 1/4 percentage point over the year, and raise employment 200,000 by the fourth quarter. Of course, these effects would reverse after 2012 following the expiration of the benefits. The hope, then, is that the economy gains enough momentum in 2012 to keep growing strongly in 2013 when the benefits expire. Otherwise, the issue of yet another extension of unemployment benefits surely will be re-visited.

    Furthermore, there is a strong irony here. Recent research suggests that emergency unemployment benefits have increased the unemployment rate by raising the labor force and perhaps by reducing the intensity of job search. Our own estimate is that these benefits currently boost the labor force enough to raise the unemployment rate 0.6 percentage point. Hence, extending unemployment benefits for another year will raise GDP growth and employment modestly, but also prevent an even larger decline in the labor force and hence a decline in the unemployment rate.[1]

    EXTENDING THE PAYROLL TAX HOLIDAY
    Extending the current holiday on the employee share of Social Security taxes through 2012 would, roughly speaking, cost $120 billion, boost real GDP growth 1/2 percentage point over the year, and raise employment 400,000 by the fourth quarter, assuming (as we do) that employers don't use the holiday as an opportunity to limit raises and or bonuses. Expanding the holiday to include the employer share of Social Security taxes would double the cost but not the stimulus, unless employers passed their tax savings on to workers. In our modeling, a cut in the employer share of payroll taxes goes almost entirely into profits with little effect on either GDP or employment. Hence, we rate expanding the payroll tax holiday to include the employer share of Social Security taxes as an ineffective way to stimulate aggregate demand and hence to boost employment.

    Some argue that reducing payroll taxes will encourage hiring independent of any impact on employment through aggregate demand. At full employment a permanent reduction in payroll taxes could coax forth additional labor supply while inducing a substitution of labor for capital (which, incidentally, would tend to reduce capital expenditures-an important component of aggregate demand). However, with employment constrained by a lack of aggregate demand, the principal effect on hiring of a temporary reduction in payroll taxes would be to convince employers to pull hiring forward from 2013 (or beyond) because the certain tax benefits of hiring in 2012 exceed the expected benefits of delaying the hire until 2013 or later. It is next to impossible to assess for how many employers this calculus favors hiring sooner than later. However, with the consensus forecast now showing little cyclical improvement in the economy over the coming year, and with little risk of a labor shortage anytime soon, we expect most employers to conclude that it remains a bad time to hire, even with the tax benefit.

    A JOBS TAX CREDIT
    The President reportedly is considering a tax credit based on the net change of a firm's workforce over a year. Such a credit would have to be carefully designed to prevent firms from "gaming" it. In addition, to have maximum immediate impact, the credit would have to be temporary. Ironically, if maintained long enough, such a credit would, by reducing the relative cost of hiring workers from a growing labor force, encourage firms to substitute labor for capital, thereby reducing labor productivity and hence real wages-probably not the intent! As a temporary measure a jobs tax credit could, like the payroll tax holiday just discussed, encourage firms to pull forward hiring forward from 2013 (or beyond) if the certain tax benefits of hiring now exceed the expected benefits of hiring later. Hence, we have the same guarded assessment of the jobs tax credit as we do of the payroll tax holiday.


    EXTENDING EXPENSING
    Special expensing provisions for businesses are slated to expire at the end of this year. Extending these provisions would lower the cost of capital, stimulate investment spending and hence aggregate demand and employment, but also induce a largely offsetting substitution away from labor towards capital. The net effect is a relatively small boost to employment. We estimate that extending the expensing provisions through 2012 would boost real GDP growth by about 0.1 percentage point, with a change in employment that, by the end of next year, is lost in the rounding.


    INFRASTRUCTURE SPENDING
    Reports suggest that the President may propose spending tens of billions of dollars to renovate the nation's public schools. Whatever the project, infrastructure spending certainly stimulates aggregate demand and employment, and also has a relatively high short-run multiplier. Furthermore, especially at the current cost of federal debt, there surely are infrastructure projects with a positive net return to society in the long run. However, as we think was learned following the enactment of the 2009 stimulus bill, there are fewer "shovel-ready" projects than once argued. Given delays arising from environmental issues and local battles over eminent domain, as well as lengthy construction timetables, the spend-out schedules for new infrastructure programs can span the better part of a decade.

    For example, suppose Congress appropriates for public construction $50 billion - a lot in today's partisan political climate, and more than appropriated under the 2009 stimulus bill. Spend-out schedules shown by the Congressional Budget Office for infrastructure spending suggest that in the first full year following the appropriation of funds, perhaps no more than 15% of the total (or $7.5 billion) would actually be spent. Assuming a multiplier of 2, this would raise real GDP by less than 0.1% at the end of one year. Through a typical Okun's law, this would raise employment by roughly 75,000. The peak employment effect would occur in the second and third years, but would still reach only about 125,000. This is just one month's growth of employment, even in today's weak economy.

    If public works projects are worthwhile as long-run investments, now is certainly an opportune time to start them. However, infrastructure spending cannot jump-start near-term hiring unless ramped up at a pace and on a scale that, outside of wartime, would be unprecedented. Some economists, like Princeton's Paul Krugman, advocate exactly this policy, but in today's political climate it simply won't happen.


    JOB TRAINING PROGRAM
    Press reports also suggest that the President's plan will target the long-term unemployed, and he has lauded a program in Georgia, called Georgia Works, under which participating companies, at no cost to themselves, train workers for eight weeks at the end of which companies can offer trainees jobs or not. During the training, workers can receive unemployment benefits as well as a modest stipend to cover transportation and other out-of-pocket expenses. Since 2003, about 1/4 of participating workers eventually were hired by the companies that trained them, and 60% quickly found gainful employment somewhere.

    Long stints of unemployment erode workers' skills, earnings, and morale, so a program that improves the match of skills supplied and demanded in labor markets seems appealing. It could help reduce structural unemployment. Still, it is unrealistic to think that Georgia Works could be quickly replicated nationwide; it certainly would be expensive to fund and administer. There also are legitimate concerns regarding design and effectiveness. Any such program must prevent firms from repeatedly exploiting what amounts to free labor. Labor economists have not studied Georgia Works sufficiently to know whether participating workers would have found jobs anyway. With unemployment currently so high, a ready supply of qualified job applicants might undermine the perceived value to employers of the free training. Furthermore, training does not address the issue of insufficient final demand. The take-up rate on such a program could be disappointingly low if, in this weak economy, firms aren't looking to hire even a well-trained worker.


    LINKING SHORT RUN AND LONG RUN
    The President would be correct to link short-term stimulus with credible long-run deficit reduction. Without the latter, the former cannot be enacted. And, financial markets (not to mention S&P!) could react badly to the cost of a short-term jobs bill not matched by a convincing willingness to pay for it later. The more near-term stimulus the President requests, the more long-term deficit reduction he must seek and, hence, the more likely the long-term deficit reduction must include tax hikes opposed by Republicans and entitlement cuts opposed by Democrats. Therefore, a dilemma for the President is that the more stimulus he requests the greater the chance of a political deadlock that precludes any jobs bill at all.


    SUMMING UP
    Temporarily extending the current payroll tax holiday, emergency unemployment benefit, and business tax breaks will temporarily boost GDP and hence employment, albeit modestly. For temporary training programs and hiring incentives to have much impact now, firms must be confident that when the temporary programs and incentives expire, economic conditions will validate the decision to hire earlier rather than later. In today's economy, there's certainly no guarantee this will occur. For infrastructure spending to make a big dent in the unemployment rate, it would have to be done rapidly and on a scale that is impossible in today's political climate. In sum, and disappointing as it may be to unemployed Americans, there simply are limits to what a jobs bill can achieve today.


    [1] See Macroeconomic Advisers' Macro Focus, "Allowing Extended UI Benefits to Expire in 2012 Could Lower NAIRU by 2/3 of a Percentage Point & Other Effects on Unemployment and the Labor Force" (Forthcoming). Our current forecast, which assumes unemployment benefits are not extended, incorporates a related decline in the unemployment rate over 2012. This explain why our forecast shows declining unemployment even in the face of very sluggish GDP growth.


    This is from a commentary that was published on August 24, 2011.

    Contact Macroeconomic Advisers


  7. Contact Macroeconomic Advisers



  8. Contact Macroeconomic Advisers

  9. The Wall Street Journal reported today that, according to “several people familiar with administration deliberations,” the President will nominate Richard Clarida and Jeremy Stein to the Federal Reserve Board.
    • Congratulations to the nominees and kudos to the President, the team advising him, and the Republicans, to the extent that this is the outcome of a “deal.”
    • Both are first-rate economists and bring expertise ensuring that they would make valuable contributions at the Board and at the FOMC.
    • It was irresponsible to leave the Board so understaffed for so long, but we appreciate the challenge of getting anyone confirmed for anything in today’s political climate.
    • These are superb appointments. It’s hard to think of better choices! It was worth the wait!
    If confirmed, Richard Clarida and Jeremy Stein will bring substantial economics and finance expertise, market savvy, and international perspective to the Board.
    • Jeremy Stein is a professor of economics at Harvard University. He served earlier in the Obama Administration as a senior advisor to the Treasury Secretary and was on the staff of the National Economic Council. His specialties include finance, monetary policy, risk management, and banking. He brings a set of skills and background that the FOMC has not always, indeed rarely, had.
    • Richard Clarida is a professor of economics at the School of International and Public Affairs at Columbia University and, since 2006, an executive vice president at PIMCO. He was the Assistant Treasury Secretary for Economic Policy in the George W. Bush administration. His focus has been on economic policy, the global and U.S. economic outlook, international capital flows, and the maturity structure of U.S. debt. The last would be especially useful at the FOMC today!
    One is a Republican; the other is a Democrat. Who cares (other than the Democrats and Republicans, of course)?
    • We hope that this “bipartisan” approach will facilitate confirmation by the Senate.
    • Political affiliation may well have been part of the nomination calculus, but, in this case, the politics stops at the door of the Eccles building.
    • We have been saying that the Chairman and Vice Chair deserve some playmates. Hopefully, they just got two!
    Does this strengthen the position of the Chairman, especially after the three dissents by bank presidents at the August FOMC meeting?
    • We don’t think so. As we have said in the past, the Chairman is the decider. That has been the case, and that will continue to be the case if Jeremy Stein and Richard Clarida are nominated and confirmed.
    • While one of Meyer’s Laws of Voting (#3: There shall not be more than two dissents) took a hit with the three dissents, we still stand by #1: Board members shall not dissent!2
    • If confirmed, the two new members will be excellent team players and follow the FOMC tradition of consensus voting. They will bring much to the table and surely help the Chairman make better decisions.
    The bottom line is: The Board and FOMC would be significantly strengthened by the two nominees.
    • The addition of Richard Clarida and Jeremy Stein to the Board would make this one of the strongest Boards in the recent history of the FOMC.
    • As strong as the Board was when Larry was there, this one might become even stronger given Clarida’s and Stein’s unquestioned expertise in financial markets, monetary policy, and economic matters.










    Contact Macroeconomic Advisers

  10. Consistent with our expectations, the FOMC started easing through communication, though much more forcefully than we had anticipated.

    This is from a commentary that was published on August 9, 2011.

    Contact Macroeconomic Advisers
Picture
Picture
Subscribe
Subscribe
Labels
Blog Archive
Text
Text


Loading
Dynamic Views theme. Powered by Blogger. Report Abuse.