1. The U.S. fiscal situation and heavy issuance of fixed-rate debt by financial institutions have been offered as possible explanations for a negative ten-year swap spread.

    Click here to contact Macroeconomic Advisers


    Bookmark and Share



  2. The House Financial Services Committee held a hearing entitled, “Unwinding Emergency Federal Reserve Liquidity Programs and Implications for Economic Recovery.” Panel Two includes Dr. Larry Meyer, Vice Chairman, Macroeconomic Advisers.

    Click here to contact Macroeconomic Advisers


    Bookmark and Share

  3. Unwinding Emergency Federal Reserve Liquidity Programs and the Federal Reserve’s Extraordinarily Accommodative Monetary Policy: Implications for Economic Recovery

    Laurence H. Meyer*

    Vice Chair

    Macroeconomic Advisers

    before the

    Committee on Financial Services

    U.S. House of Representatives

    March 25, 2010

    *This testimony represents my views, and not necessarily the views of Macroeconomic Advisers or my colleagues at Macroeconomic Advisers.


    Chairman Frank, Ranking Member Bachus, and other members of the Committee. Thank you for giving me this opportunity to discuss questions related to the already completed exit from the Fed’s emergency liquidity facilities and plans to exit from its extraordinarily accommodative monetary policy.


    When and Why Did the Federal Reserve Close its Emergency Liquidity Facilities?

    As Chairman Bernanke explained to you in his earlier testimony [1], the Fed has already closed virtually all its emergency liquidity facilities.[2] How did the Fed do this? It’s important to know that these facilities basically closed on their own, as was always the plan. Requests for funding declined and then virtually stopped as markets healed. In essence, all that was left for the Fed to do was just to close the door and terminate the facilities. They are already history.


    When the history is written, it will surely conclude that these programs proved to be extremely effective. They prevented an even worse financial collapse than would otherwise have occurred, and hence an even deeper recession.


    At the outset of the financial panic, there was an unprecedented liquidity squeeze. Financial institutions that always fund themselves in short-term money markets and invest in illiquid longer-term assets found that they could no longer do so because of perceived insolvency risk and uncertainty about where the risks were located or concentrated. The Fed and other central banks, often in cooperation, acted, as is their role, as liquidity providers of last resort. Their swift, creative, aggressive, and sometimes coordinated actions clearly prevented a fire sale of illiquid assets. Failing to provide this liquidity would have immediately pushed the financial system to at least closer to the edge of an abyss.


    The last step in the process of liquidity normalization, and one that was not well understood by the markets, was an increase in the discount rate, specifically an increase in the spread of the discount rate over the funds rate. This spread had been 100 basis points before the crisis, and was shrunk to 25 basis points as part of the Fed’s efforts to inject a massive amount of liquidity. The Fed in this case sought to further encourage banks to access the discount window, its traditional vehicle for meeting emergency needs of depository institutions, and counter the perceived stigma associated with doing so. The spread has now been increased by 25 basis points to 50 basis points. Further increases are likely, and we expect the Fed to move the spread back further in the direction of its pre-crisis level.


    What is the relationship between closing the emergency liquidity programs and monetary policy exit, specifically the first hike in the funds rate?

    None. Chairman Bernanke fully explained this distinction to you in his testimony.


    Raising the discount rate was entirely part of the process to normalize liquidity arrangements, specifically to close emergency liquidity facilities that were no longer needed. Chairman Bernanke emphasized, as clearly as he possibly could, that this increase in the discount rate had absolutely nothing to do with the timing of exit from the near-zero funds rate, and was not therefore a signal about that timing.


    This was the one of the early tests of Fed communication. This was also a test of how well the market listens to and understands that communication. In any case, Chairman Bernanke did very well, the markets did not.


    What are the tools the Fed will use to unwind its extraordinarily accommodative monetary policy?

    There are three actions that define the Fed’s exit from its extraordinarily accommodative policy: actively withdrawing reserves, raising the policy rate, and shrinking the Fed’s balance sheet.


    The Fed will withdraw reserves by executing reverse repos involving Treasury and agency securities and by offering term deposits to depository institutions. It will raise the policy rate by increasing the interest rate paid on reserves (IOR), and it will shrink the balance sheet passively through redemptions and prepayments (runoff), and perhaps actively by selling securities, with an emphasis on MBS.


    What will be the sequence of steps the Federal Reserve will take to unwind its extraordinarily accommodative policy?

    The first step is preparation, and this is already well under way, but not yet complete. The preparatory steps under way include the NY Fed’s small-scale operations with reverse repos to test the plumbing, the infrastructure for its ultimate use of reverse repos to drain reserves. So far, it has conducted such operations only with Treasury and agency debt as collateral. It will soon do so for MBS. The Fed has also expanded the counterparties who can participate in reverse repos with it, and will likely expand this list further, to help the market absorb the large amount of reverse repos that it wants to be prepared to do. The Board also requested comments for a proposal to establish a term deposit facility, another way the Fed will ultimately drain reserves. It is now revising that proposal in light of the comments received. The Fed should be in a position to use these tools to begin to drain reserves by the second half of this year.[3] The NY Fed has clearly communicated to the markets that it believes that it is prudent to ensure that this infrastructure is in place so that the FOMC can exit whenever appropriate, but that this preparation has no implications for the timing of the first increase in the policy rate.


    The second step is to revise the policy guidance contained in the FOMC statement. That guidance is intended to give markets advance notice that the time is approaching for an increase in the policy rate. A change in the guidance will be the first definitive signal that an increase in the funds rate may come sooner rather than later. Today the key phrases in that guidance are that economic conditions will likely warrant an “exceptionally low” funds rate for an “extended period.” “Exceptionally low” means an unchanged near-zero funds rate. “Extended period” is vaguer and means different things to different members of the Committee. But it is generally interpreted to mean six months or longer, a period explicitly indicated by a few members of the Committee. Chairman Bernanke will not be pinned down so precisely. In any case, these are the two phrases that will have to be adjusted—presumably in two stages—as the FOMC gets closer to raising the funds rate.


    The last three steps in the Fed’s exit, as they were explained to you in Chairman Bernanke’s testimony, are: draining reserves to move away from today’s super-abundant level, raising the policy rate to withdraw the extraordinary degree of monetary accommodation today, and shrinking the balance sheet which, during the crisis period, more than doubled in size. Chairman Bernanke also presented you with an outline of the likely exit strategy, including the tools to be used, and the sequence in which the three steps could be taken: first, start to drain reserves, next, raise the policy rate (but not much later than the beginning of the reserve draining), and still later, if at all necessary, sell MBS to shrink its balance sheet.


    The FOMC generally believes that reserve management is a very important complement to the direct role of IOR in raising market rates. In principle, raising the IOR rate allows the Fed to raise short-term interest rates, including the funds rate, independent of how large reserves are at the time. This is the case because no bank should be willing to lend at a funds rate lower than the rate it can earn by depositing the funds at a Reserve Bank. The IOR rate should therefore be a tight floor for the funds rate.


    However, in practice, the funds rate has consistently traded soft to the IOR rate.[4] The Fed believes it can tighten this relationship by reserve management, that is, by reducing reserves, to shrink and stabilize, and hopefully ultimately close, the gap between the funds rate and the IOR rate. This is viewed as desirable, in part because it will allow the Fed to target the funds rate, much in the same way it had done in the past.


    Because it would like to tighten the relationship between these rates before it begins to raise rates, the Fed prefers to start removing reserves before it hikes the IOR rate. However, even beginning to actively withdraw reserves will be taken as a definitive signal of an impending increase in the IOR rate, no matter what guidance the Fed offers at the time. So the FOMC plans to start this draining only when it is pretty sure that an increase in the funds rate is around the corner. So the first part of the sequence is to drain reserves first, and only slightly later, to raise rates.


    The final step may be to sell MBS. This is the most controversial of the steps. Several on the FOMC do not see the urgency in shrinking the balance sheet faster than would happen passively through runoff. They prefer not to risk a very adverse market response that many in the markets expect in this case. This is where my sympathies lie. However, if the FOMC does sell MBS back to the market, Chairman Bernanke told you that this would take place relatively late, only when the economy is in a sustainable recovery and once markets are back closer to normal. This would also likely take place well after the FOMC begins to raise rates, and will almost certainly be gradual and very well communicated in advance to the markets. Under these circumstances, the possibility of a very adverse market response will be significantly diminished. Still, the majority appears to believe that just allowing the balance sheet to shrink passively and slowly by runoff alone will take longer than they prefer, a minimum of five to seven years, and to get it fully done, it could take a couple of decades. On the other hand, most market participants believe that there would be absolutely no adverse response to taking such a long time. In this case, I believe that relying on runoff alone is the most sensible direction.


    Can the unwinding efforts be carried out without unwanted inflationary effects and, if so, how can this be accomplished?

    Yes, by exiting at the right time. I cannot and neither can the FOMC guarantee that the Fed will exit at the right time. This is its biggest challenge. The Fed is operating in unchartered waters: It has never had such a challenging exit. Don’t expect the Fed to be perfect. Nobody is perfect. However, we are fortunate to have Chairman Bernanke navigating the ship. Nobody could do a better job of getting the timing right. But there will still be a debate that will linger virtually forever about whether the Fed did in fact exit at just the right time.

    The right time, of course, means not too early, so as not to the stunt the nascent recovery and when inflation is still “too low” (and expected to remain so for some time), and not too late, resulting in unwanted inflation.


    I will focus on the inflation risk, as this is what you asked about. Let’s start by highlighting three different forecasts: my firm’s, the consensus, and the FOMC’s. Ours is the most optimistic about growth, but all three share one property: The unemployment rate will remain very elevated for a very long time. It is likely to be above 9% at the end of this year and perhaps 8% - 8½% at the end of next year. That is relative to a full employment level that we and the FOMC place at 5% or slightly higher. Core inflation is already below 1½% and appears to still be falling. We expect it to be 1% this year and slightly lower next year. The last FOMC forecast showed inflation just below 1½% for the same period. Let’s assume that the FOMC tightened at the end of this year. What would you be asking Chairman Bernanke at the Monetary Policy Testimony in mid-February 2011? Would you be asking why the Fed waited so long, until the unemployment rate was already close to 9% and core inflation had already stabilized near 1%, before you tightened? I doubt it. So I hope you can understand why the majority of members of the FOMC are not worried about inflation today and won’t be for some time. As a result, we don’t expect the FOMC to raise the policy rate until mid-2011, and, if the pessimists are right about growth, it could be much later.[6]


    It is interesting, nevertheless, that some, including a few very well respected economists, worry that inflation will be very high over the medium term. Some even believe that we are headed to hyperinflation. There is no chance that either outcome could happen as long as the Fed remains independent. So let’s be clear where the risk of very high inflation comes from. It is not the Fed. It is you.


    We could get to very high inflation in one of two ways: a major and dramatic but almost inconceivable policy error by the Fed, essentially a total disregard for its price stability mandate, or action by the Congress to force the Fed to monetize deficits to avoid soaring interest rates that would otherwise occur. The former simply could never happen. But the latter is entirely up to you. It is precisely to avoid such an outcome that governments around the world have delegated monetary policy decisions to independent central banks. Given this concern, Congress should be careful to avoid doing anything that even gives the appearance of infringing on the independence of the Fed, including authorizing the GAO to audit monetary policy.


    Have the Fed’s extraordinary monetary policy actions worked?

    The Fed’s extraordinary policies include first pushing the funds rate to a near-zero level and then keeping it there for an extended period, along with turning to nonconventional policies once it faced the zero nominal bound, specifically “credit-easing” policies to provide further stimulus.


    The FOMC has had a near-zero rate policy only because it cannot lower short-term interest rates into negative territory. If it could, it would have. In the absence of that option, monetary policy should be understood as being dramatically restrictive, even at the near-zero rate. We estimate that the Fed would have to lower the funds rate to -4% today to align it with the appropriate degree of stimulus. Absent being able to do this, the only option was to implement unconventional policies, despite the great uncertainty of how well these would work. The major form of nonconventional policy is “credit-easing” policies. Credit-easing policies specifically involve intervening in and buying assets, especially those with longer maturities, in markets where the flow of credit is impaired as a result of the financial crisis, with the hope of both increasing the flow of credit and improving the terms on which credit is offered, or otherwise moving to lower longer-term rates relative to the near zero funds rate. In this episode, the Fed refers to these policies as Long Term Asset Purchases, and these include both the purchase of longer-term Treasury securities to push down long-term rates relative to short-term rates, and MBS purchases to lower the spread between mortgage rates and longer-term Treasuries. The Fed has already ended its Treasury securities purchase program and will end its MBS program next week. The decision to end programs that were providing additional stimulus mainly reflected concern that further expanding the balance sheet would make exit even more challenging and increase the risk of a policy error, and therefore unwanted inflation.


    Lowering the funds rate to near zero certainly helped lean against the recession and then support recovery. The Fed did as much as it could possibly do with its conventional instruments. The effectiveness of credit easing policies is more controversial and different economists reach different conclusions. Qualitatively, we agree with the NY Fed’s recent study which estimates that the purchase of Treasury and agency securities had important effects, lowering longer-term interest rates and narrowing mortgage spreads.[7]


    Nevertheless, there is considerable skepticism, including some inside the FOMC, that renewed purchases of longer term Treasuries and MBS would be successful in providing further stimulus. This assessment is relevant to how much additional stimulus the Fed could achieve by, for example, renewing its asset purchase program, if the economy were to slip into a double dip recession. The realistic answer is not much.


    If monetary policy is not sufficient to spur economic growth, what options are available?

    Here the answer is obvious. Once the Fed is driven to a near-zero funds rate, what we call the “zero nominal bound”, the burden of stabilization policy shifts to you. This is very challenging given the difficulty of Congress delivering action in a timely manner. This is why the conventional wisdom has been to encourage Congress not to try to engage in short-run stabilization policy, and leave that entirely to the Fed. But given the Fed is at the zero nominal bound, the only option for significant further stimulus is fiscal stimulus. Fortunately, in the current episode, Congress did pass a timely and sizeable fiscal stimulus. One can argue about the size and composition, but one cannot argue that fiscal stimulus was not needed. Most economists, as reported by the CBO, believe that the fiscal stimulus was effective. Our estimate, and this is close to the consensus view, is that it raised growth by 1½ percentage points from the third quarter of last year through (prospectively) the second quarter of this year.


    However, the stimulus is almost completely temporary, as was appropriately the intention. As a result, the positive effect will reverse and the effect will turn negative, even by the end of this year. This swing is one reason why forecasters generally see as the real test of the recovery the performance of the economy after the middle of the year when fiscal stimulus first diminishes and then reverses. To be sure, while a permanent stimulus would have been more effective, it would have been irresponsible to do so, given that the budget deficit is already on an unsustainable course, as everyone knows.


    It is nevertheless true that the view that the stimulus package was effective is not universally held among economists: One uses different models and gets different results. I should point out, though, that many of the contrarian views that are politically driven don’t really hold up to even a very modest degree of scrutiny.



    [1] Ben Bernanke, “Federal Reserve's Exit Strategy,” Testimony before the Committee on Financial Services, U.S. House of Representatives, February 10, 2010. The hearing was cancelled because of snow, but the Fed released the testimony on the day of the planned testimony.

    [2] These include the Term Auction Facility (TAF), the Primary Dealer Credit Facility (PDCF), the Term Securities Lending Facility (TSLF), the Term Securities Lending Facility Options Program (TOP), the Commercial Paper Funding Facility (CPFF), the Asset-Backed Commercial Paper (ABCP) Money Market Mutual Fund Liquidity Facility (AMLF), the Money Market Investor Funding Facility (MMIFF), as well as the currency swap arrangements with foreign central banks.

    [3] This was reported in a talk by Brian Sack, Executive Vice President of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York and head of its Markets Group. See Brian Sack, “Preparing for a Smooth (Eventual) Exit,” March 8, 2010.

    [4] It is now well understood why this is the case. The GSEs traditionally are lenders in the federal funds market, but are not allowed to hold interest-earning deposits at the Fed. As a result, they put downward pressure on the funds rate relative to the IOR rate.

    [5] Gagnon et. al., “Large-Scale Asset Purchases by the Federal Reserve: Did They Work?” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report No. 441, March 2010.

    [6] The risk of inflation is an issue that almost always separates the hawks from the doves in the FOMC; in this case, the hawks versus the coalition of the center and doves. This has, in part, to do with the relative weights each assigns to each of the two mandates—promoting full employment and promoting price stability—although everyone agrees that there is no conflict between these objectives in the longer term, and nobody on the Committee would tolerate unwanted inflation for long. The other principal factor that distinguishes doves’ and hawks’ views on inflation, and the more important one today, is what model best explains inflation in the short and medium term. I won’t go into the details, but this issue comes down to whether you favor a monetarist model or a Phillips curve model in the short run, and whether you believe the Fed is going to set the funds rate over time to ensure that inflation converges to its target (as work on policy rules suggest has been the case over the past two decades). I am, as Chairman Frank no doubt well remembers, in the Phillips curve camp, along with the majority of the FOMC.

    [7] Gagnon et. al., “Large-Scale Asset Purchases by the Federal Reserve: Did They Work?” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report No. 441, March 2010.



    Click here to contact Macroeconomic Advisers


    Bookmark and Share

  4. We introduce a simple framework that, we believe, captures the essence of prevailing Fed thinking on exit strategy, particularly with respect to the question of how to tighten policy in an environment of overabundant reserves. Our framework describes the Fed's likely strategy for addressing what we call the soggy floor problem: the tendency of the funds rate to trade soft to the IOR rate. We supplement our analysis with empirical results.

    Click here to contact Macroeconomic Advisers


    Bookmark and Share


  5. Balance on the Board

    Peter Diamond and Sarah Bloom Raskin, the President’s presumptive Fed Board nominees, are both impressive individuals who would bring something special and perhaps unique to the Board. But neither has significant expertise or experience in both macroeconomic analysis and monetary policy.
    • Diamond and Raskin would respectively bring fresh thinking and front-line experience with bank supervision to the Fed. But the resulting Board will have only two members who are monetary policy experts. That raises concern about whether the Board’s composition will be appropriately balanced, relative to its responsibilities. 
    • It is unlikely that either presumptive nominee would have any effect on monetary policy decisions, immediately, and perhaps for a long time. 
    • I am hoping for better balance on the Board when the next seat becomes available. 
    Given the importance to our country of the Federal Reserve’s dual mandate of full employment and price stability, U.S. Presidents have always been mindful of their responsibility for ensuring that the Board includes sufficient people with the background, skills, and experience to immediately step in and contribute to monetary policy decisions. Of course, the Board has other responsibilities, such as bank supervision and regulation and consumer protection, so nominations also have to reflect the diversity of those, perhaps too numerous, missions. The challenge for Presidents has always been to find an appropriate balance in the composition of the Board so that it can effectively carry out its various functions. How many Board members with sufficient monetary policy expertise do we need so that the Federal Reserve can dutifully and optimally fulfill its dual mandate? The arithmetic of Fed Board appointments is never easy; it’s not an exact science. Nonetheless, given the Board’s current composition—even after assuming that Janet Yellen is formally nominated and confirmed as Vice Chair—the President’s reported choices to fill the two remaining governor’s slots make me wonder whether the result would be a Board whose collective expertise in monetary policy matters adds up to its dual-mandate responsibilities.

    With the nominations that the President is apparently ready to make, the Board will finally be back to full capacity. From the perspective of managing monetary policy and promoting financial stability, the President has already made two superb decisions: the re-nomination of Ben Bernanke and the expected nomination of Janet Yellen as Vice Chair. The President could not have done better. His earlier, and first, nominee to the Board, Dan Tarullo, was also an excellent choice. Governor Tarullo has provided invaluable leadership in the oversight of the Board’s responsibilities for bank regulation and supervision, and financial stability more broadly. To be sure, Peter Diamond and Sarah Bloom have impeccable credentials, and there is plenty to say on their behalf, including why they would bring something special to the Board. But I wonder, again, about the balance of the new Board: There will be seven Board members. Of the seven, assuming President Yellen, Professor Diamond, and Commissioner Raskin are formally nominated by President Obama and confirmed by the U.S. Senate, five would not have special expertise in monetary policy matters. That leaves only two with the requisite background.

    Let me set Janet Yellen’s potential nomination aside for the moment—I wrote about it the week before last—and focus on the Board’s two other vacancies.[1] My concerns here have absolutely nothing to do with the competence of Peter Diamond and Sarah Bloom Raskin. It is not about them at all.

    To make my case for better balance on the Board, I propose that we consider the backgrounds and experience of the two nominees. I will start with Peter Diamond since I have at least some prior knowledge of him. He was already a professor of economics at MIT when I was a graduate student there. He is only a few years older than I am but he was already a distinguished professor and a leader in the field of theoretical public finance at that time. My experience at MIT was actually colored to a degree by his presence there. For example, I once grew a beard so I could play him in the students’ skit during the department’s holiday celebration. Also, on the first day that I was in the graduate student library, I went to the recent dissertations section to see what it would take to get a Ph.D. at MIT. My eyes naturally gravitated to the thinnest thesis, which happened to be Diamond’s. When I opened it, to my surprise, the only English words, among a sea of equations and Greek letters, were “To my Mom.” Well, that is a bit of an exaggeration, but not much.

    Peter Diamond is an absolutely brilliant professor and, in addition, a well-respected expert on social security and pensions. If the President’s objective were to elevate the collective IQ of the Board, then he will unquestionably do so by nominating Professor Diamond. Moreover, if the President were putting together a commission to return Social Security to long-run sustainability, he could hardly make a better appointment.

    Maybe it is just my bias toward MIT economists and perhaps toward very smart people in general, but I have to admit that the nomination of Peter Diamond is at least intriguing. It is sort of like going into the NFL draft (one of my favorite events of the sports year) and being confronted with the age-old question of whether to fill a need or take the best player available. You really need a quarterback (in this case a monetary policy expert). But you really love the talent and potential of another player (Peter Diamond), though you don’t really know whether he will end up as a running back, a wide receiver, or a safety, or even a valuable member of the team. What do you do? Hard to say! It depends on the circumstances. If you go for the high-risk, high-reward player, you may be fried by the sports’ experts (me in this case). Only time will tell if you made the right decision. OK, I admit I am very risk averse, and perhaps parochial, and perhaps I just want instant gratification (in terms of contributions to the Board’s core missions). But it seems to me that three macro/money Board members out of seven would be a better balance than two out of seven.

    But times change. New thinking may be just what is called for, and if you wanted the best player available who might just bring that to the Board, you might get a Peter Diamond. Indeed, you might nominate Peter Diamond himself! I can also well imagine, after the struggle to confirm Ben Bernanke’s re-nomination, that the Administration was wary of appointing just another macroeconomist to the Board. After all, some political minds might think that the Board had plenty of macroeconomists in the years leading up to the crisis! So this may be a stroke of political genius, and the last thing anyone ever accused me of being was a political genius. Perhaps this is about my inability to think outside the box, but I never would have even thought of Professor Diamond in connection with the Board. Still, this will at least be fun to watch, and I really hope I will have undervalued the importance of the best player available and the contributions that Peter Diamond will ultimately make to the Board.

    Turning to the other nominee, I have never met Sarah Bloom Raskin, and I had never heard of her before her nomination. But it is obvious that she has a superb background and awesome resume, including positions at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York and the Senate Banking Committee. Currently, as Maryland’s Commissioner of Financial Regulation, she oversees both the supervision and examination of Maryland’s state-chartered banks and the state’s consumer financial protection provisions. Here, too, my main concern is that she is not (like me) a money-macro kind of person, although it has been pointed out to me (and I have a copy in hand) that she wrote her undergraduate thesis on monetary policy targeting. (Mine was on applying Henry George’s single tax idea to property taxes in New Haven!)

    In any case, Commissioner Raskin’s reputation is especially strong as a “consumer advocate,” and, while this is of course only speculation, it is in this capacity that I expect the President nominated her. After all, the Board currently has no shortage of members with regulatory and financial institution expertise: As noted above, the President’s first nominee—Governor Tarullo—is an expert in banking regulation and supervision, and two other members of the Board—Governors Duke and Warsh—have backgrounds in banking and financial institutions more broadly. I take no issue with the fact that the commissioner is superbly suited for a position as a consumer advocate. In addition, she does add a new dimension to the Board with respect to supervisory expertise: She has actually been on the front line of bank supervision and regulation and, as such, she would bring strong and relevant experience and knowledge to the Board.

    I also don’t disagree with the notion that, as long as the Board has responsibility for consumer protection, it is reasonable that one of the Board slots should be filled by someone with expertise in this area. However, it is not yet clear whether the Board will retain this capacity. Indeed, the President’s own reform proposal would take this responsibility entirely away from the Fed. Senator Dodd’s reform proposal also has direct relevance to whether there needs to be someone on the Board with expertise in and experience with consumer protection. The Dodd proposal would establish an independent consumer protection agency, with a Director appointed by the President and confirmed by the Senate. That agency would be housed at the Federal Reserve Board, but the Director’s position would be separate and distinct from that of a Federal Reserve Governor, with no Board oversight and no votes required of the Board. (Sarah Bloom Raskin would certainly be an outstanding appointment by the President as Director of such an independent agency.)

    My main point here is that no one knows which reform proposal will prevail: the President’s, Senator Dodd’s, or somebody else’s. It might therefore be premature to nominate a consumer advocate to the Fed Board at this point, especially when there are so few Board members with expertise in monetary policy.

    As an aside, I find the senator’s proposal with respect to the Consumer Protection Bureau quite bizarre. If the new bureau will really be an independent agency, why is it to be housed at the Board? Isn’t this sure to create confusion about the Fed’s role in consumer protection? Indeed, there have already been many commentaries suggesting that this proposal would strengthen the Fed’s hands in consumer protection. So there is clearly confusion as to whether this authority has been taken away or strengthened. Could it be the case that all that the Fed would be left with is reputation risk with respect to the implementation and enforcement of consumer protection laws?

    Let me add that Commissioner Raskin’s appointment, too, might well be another stroke of political genius. She is also out of the mold of recent Board members, in that she has front-line experience as a bank supervisor (this may please the Republicans), and she is a very articulate consumer advocate (this will surely please the Democrats). It could be argued, though I almost never think in such crude political terms, that the two appointments should sail through their confirmations, both because they have impeccable credentials and aren’t like current and recent Board members.

    Let us assume that the reported potential nominations of President Yellen, Professor Diamond, and Commissioner Raskin are made official and confirmed by the U.S. Senate. Relative to the two monetary policy experts on the Board (Bernanke and Yellen), we will have half as many Board members who are consumer advocates (Raskin), half as many who are experts in theoretical public finance (Diamond), and twice as many members who have expertise in financial institutions or directly in bank supervision (Duke, Raskin, Tarullo, and Warsh). This just doesn’t seem to me as the right balance. But this is not an insoluble problem. It is rumored, but I have no first-hand knowledge here, that Governor Warsh will leave the Board within one or two years. That would be an opportunity to improve the balance on the Board, provided the Administration nominates a money-macro person at that point, hopefully a very able and distinguished one.

    There has been, of course, a lot of speculation on how these appointments would change the balance on the Board and FOMC with respect to monetary policy. Most of this discussion has been way off the mark. It seems to me that the eventual confirmation of Diamond and Raskin as Fed Governors might well exacerbate the balance of power among U.S. monetary policymakers along three dimensions. First, within the Board, it would lead to even more power, with respect to monetary policy, being concentrated with the Chairman. This would be a natural consequence of having a seven-member Board where the Chairman is only one of two members with real monetary policy expertise. It’s not that Chairman Bernanke and presumptive Vice Chair Yellen can’t do it by themselves. They surely can, but I still think that they both should have more help on the Board.

    Second, the composition of the new Board may end up making the Board staff even more influential with respect to monetary policy decisions. Other than Janet Yellen (assuming she becomes Vice Chair), staff members would be the only others in the building, at least until Peter Diamond gets up to full speed, who could help shape the Chairman’s views on monetary policy. That’s really OK too, because the staff is excellent, and because it has always played a more important role in influencing policy decisions than many Board members. But the balance between the Board and the staff will shift too much, in my opinion, to the staff in this case.

    Lastly, the influence of Reserve Bank Presidents in FOMC deliberations could also be enhanced if Diamond and Raskin were to become members of the Fed Board. After all, many of the Presidents do have the needed experience and expertise in both monetary policy making and macroeconomic analysis. Isn’t this ironic, given that the role of Reserve Banks has been much scrutinized of late, with some critics even questioning the wisdom of allowing Bank Presidents to cast a vote on monetary policy matters? I’d say that one of the many virtues of the current structure of the Federal Reserve, in this case, is that there will still be members of the FOMC, other than the Chairman and the presumptive Board Vice Chair, with backgrounds and experience well suited to deliberate on monetary policy.

    Now, let me try to correct what I see as misperceptions regarding the Diamond and Raskin nominations. There has been some chatter that the new nominees would potentially, importantly, and immediately affect monetary policy decisions, including the timing of exit from the Fed’s near-zero interest rate policy, and specifically that the new potential appointees will provide more support for the doves on the Committee and have greater sympathy for an activist FOMC, one (even) more focused on full employment than on inflation. Was there any doubt that the President would appoint members who reinforced the positions of the doves on the Committee? That is always a President’s prerogative, and that was certainly the expectation of President Clinton when he nominated me, though, it did not turn out exactly that way! But to expect Diamond and Raskin to have any influence on monetary policy, especially immediately, is to misunderstand the dynamics of the Board and the FOMC.

    Governors, after all, unlike Federal Reserve Bank Presidents, function as a team and vote as a block in FOMC deliberations: No dissents; put your case on the table, assuming you are viewed as being credible enough to have a case in the first place; then follow the Chairman. Of course there are limits to the Chairman’s reach, though these are virtually never operative: If the Chairman is in the overwhelming minority, he cannot count on the FOMC, and even the Board, to support him. But this is very unlikely in practice, and especially when the Board has so many new members. Moreover, historically, those without the requisite monetary policy experience on the FOMC simply defer to the Chairman. To sum up, the two new governors will be part of the team and of the overwhelming majority that invariably lines up with the Chairman. In my view, as bright as they are in their core areas of expertise, they will, at least initially, have no independent effect on monetary policy decisions, particularly with respect to the most challenging questions that will be facing the FOMC in the months ahead.

    I wish the two new potential appointees well, assuming the vetting goes smoothly. (This process, by the way, is much more challenging than when I was nominated. In fact, I was nominated before I was even vetted!) In any case, I congratulate them on their likely nomination to serve on the Board. I have no doubt that, if nominated and confirmed, they will find ways to put their special talents, backgrounds, and experience to good use and become very effective Board members. Indeed, they each would bring something special and perhaps unique to the Board. Moreover, I am not at all worried about the quality of monetary policy decisions, given the likely appointment of Janet Yellen to team up with Ben Bernanke. I just wish they had more immediate help, and I hope they will get it soon!

    [1] Please see our Meyer’s Musings, “Hurray!” published March 12, 2010.


    Larry Meyer

    Click here to contact Macroeconomic Advisers
    Bookmark and Share





  6. Click here to contact Macroeconomic Advisers


    Bookmark and Share

  7. The Committee kept its policy and policy guidance unchanged as we expected. “Exceptionally low” and “extended period” are still alive and well, and their life expectancy may be longer than many think.

    Click here to contact Macroeconomic Advisers


    Bookmark and Share



  8. Click here to contact Macroeconomic Advisers
    Bookmark and Share

  9. Public statements by Fed officials during this intermeeting period focused on various aspects of exit, ranging from separating monetary policy decisions from liquidity policy to highlighting that preparatory steps for exit should not be taken as an indication that the next rate hike is around the corner.

    Click here to contact Macroeconomic Advisers


    Bookmark and Share

  10. Last meeting was mostly about exit strategy; this one is likely to be dominated by a discussion of the policy language in the statement. We fully expect the Committee to retain the “exceptionally low” and “extended period” language, but we believe it will begin to talk about how that language might be changed. There will, of course, be no change in the Committee’s 0-to-25 basis-point target for the funds rate.

    Click here to contact Macroeconomic Advisers


    Bookmark and Share

Picture
Picture
Subscribe
Subscribe
Labels
Blog Archive
Text
Text


Loading
Dynamic Views theme. Powered by Blogger. Report Abuse.